Intermediate
Macroeconomics
Lecture 6
Douglas Hanley, University of Pittsburgh
In This Lecture
- How to think about consumer savings in a model
- Effect of changes in interest rate
- Effect of changes in present or future income
Consumption Savings Model
- Consider a model with only two periods: today and tomorrow
- Consumers have a certain income today ($y$), income tomorrow ($y^{\prime}$), taxes today ($t$), and taxes tomorrow ($t^{\prime}$)
- They must choose an amount to save ($s$), as well as consumption today ($c$) and consumption tomorrow ($c^{\prime}$)
Budget Constraint(s)
- Now we have two budget constraints, one for each period. Today
$$c + s = y - t$$
- And for tomorrow
$$c^{\prime} = y^{\prime} - t^{\prime} + (1+r) s$$
- Notice that saving yields a return of $1+r$, the interest rate
Moving to One Constraint
- In first period, anything you don't consume, you must save
$$s = (y - t) - c$$
- Plugging this into second period budget constraint
$$c^{\prime} = y^{\prime} - t^{\prime} + (1+r)(y - t - c)$$
- So now we have one budget constraint relating consumption today and consumption tomorrow
Lifetime Budget Constraint
- We can express this as a lifetime budget constraint
$$\begin{align*}
& c^{\prime} = y^{\prime} - t^{\prime} + (1+r)(y - t - c) \\
\Rightarrow\ & c + \frac{c^{\prime}}{1+r} = y - t + \frac{y^{\prime}-t^{\prime}}{1+r} \equiv we \longleftarrow \text{wealth}
\end{align*}$$
- This says that the present value of your consumption is equal to the present value of your after-tax income (your wealth)
- This same as Walrasian model with $p = 1$ and $p^{\prime} = \frac{1}{1+r}$
Visualizing Consumer Choices
Two "goods" are consumption today and tomorrow
Conditions for Optimality
- Remember the Walrasian model said the optimum should equate the marginal rate of substitution with the price ratio
- Here that means the interest rate, so that
$$\text{MRS}_{c,c^{\prime}} = 1 +r$$
- Give $1$ unit of consumption today $\rightarrow$ get $1+r$ units tomorrow
- This conditions means doing so wouldn't make you better or worse off
Consumption Smoothing
Consumers prefer to smooth consumption across periods
Borrowers and Lenders
Final consumption only depends on present value wealth.
Split between today and tomorrow — lender or borrower.
Increase in Current Income
What happens when your income today increases?
Permanent Income
- Your present day consumption increases by less than income increase
- Increase "unbalances" your income, so you save a bit more to smooth consumption
- The same thing is true of increases in future income: future consumption goes up but
- You will also save slightly less and consume more today
Increase in Future Income
What to do today if you got a nice job starting next year?
Time Series Implications
- Given what we have found, we would expect consumption to be smooth in the data
$$\text{Income} = \text{Consumption} + \text{Savings}$$
- If we smooth consumption, then we must do so by adjusting savings, making it more volatile
$$Vol(\text{Consumption}) < Vol(\text{Income}) < Vol(\text{Savings})$$
Types of Consumption
- Instead of savings, we can look at consumption of durables, which are things like cars and appliances
- These will act kind of like savings, since you give up current consumption to buy an appliance today for a future stream of consumption (household services)
- We will call regular consumption like food non-durables
Volatility of Consumption
Durables much more volatile than income (GDP)
Volatility of Consumption
Non-durables much smoother than income (GDP)
Temporary vs Permanent
Temporary — current income $\uparrow$, permanent — both $\uparrow$
Consumption-Savings Response
- During 2008 recession, policymakers wanted to increase demand
- Giving people money (temporary stimulus) might just result in increased savings
- Efforts were made to target those most likely to spend (due to borrowing limits)
- We'll talk later about the broader issues involved
Permanent Changes in Wealth
Movements in stock prices are correlated with non-durables
Permanent Changes in Wealth
Theory says movements in stocks should be "permanent"
Interest Rate Response
- How might a consumer respond to changes in the interest rate?
- This is slightly more nuanced the the income case
- Interest rate changes both wealth (present value of income) and prices
- So we have an income and substitution effect
Effect On Savers
Substitution effect: $A \rightarrow D$ ($r \uparrow$ so more savings)
Income effect: $D \rightarrow B$ (income $\uparrow$ so more of both)
Effect On Borrowers
Substitution effect: $A \rightarrow D$ ($r \uparrow$ so more savings)
Income effect: $D \rightarrow B$ (income $\downarrow$ so less of both)
Breaking Down Effects
- If interest rate goes up, doesn't wealth go down? Yes!
- Price variation uses Hicksian demand at old utility and new prices (min cost subject to utility unchanged)
- Moving from price modified demand to final demand?
- Residual income change depends on whether you started as saver or borrower
Savers Vs Borrowers
Summary Of Effects
- Savers
- Future consumption increases
- Current consumption/savings may rise or fall
- Borrowers
- Current consumtion falls (savings increases)
- Future consumption may rise or fall
Theoretical Underpinnings
- Suppose our consumer has utility of the form
$$U(c,c^{\prime}) = u(c) + \beta u(c^{\prime})$$
- Little $u$ is called the per-period or Bernoulli utility function
- Utility of this form is called separable
- The weight $\beta$ on the second period is called the discount rate
Intertemporal Optimization
- The problem the consumer solves is
$$\begin{align*}
\max_{c,c^{\prime}} \quad & u(c) + \beta u(c^{\prime}) \\
s.t \quad & c + \frac{c^{\prime}}{1+r} = y-t + \frac{y^{\prime}-t^{\prime}}{1+r} = we
\end{align*}$$
- We can also think about his as just choosing the savings $s$
$$\max_{s} \quad u(y-t-s) + \beta u(y^{\prime}-t^{\prime}+(1+r)s)$$
- These will always give the same answer in the end!
Optimal Savings Choice
- Let's go with the savings choice and take the derivative with respect to $s$
$$\begin{align*}
& 0 = -u_c(y-t-s) + \beta (1+r) u_c (y^{\prime}-t^{\prime}+(1+r)s) \\
\Rightarrow\ & u_c(c) = \beta (1+r) u_c(c^{\prime}) \\
\Rightarrow\ & \frac{u_c(c)}{u_c(c^{\prime})} = \beta (1+r)
\qquad \Leftrightarrow \quad MRS = \frac{u_c(c)}{\beta u_c(c^{\prime})} = 1+r
\end{align*}$$
- This is the same MRS condition I mentioned earlier and that we see in the graphs
Consumption Smoothing
- That first condition is also called the Euler condition
$$\frac{u_c(c)}{u_c(c^{\prime})} = \beta (1+r)$$
- Remember that the function $u_c(\cdot)$ is just marginal utility
- We assume that this is decreasing, so its a monotone function
- What happens when $\beta (1+r) = 1$?
$$\beta(1+r) = 1 \quad \Rightarrow \quad u_c(c) = u_c(c^{\prime}) \quad \Rightarrow \quad c = c^{\prime}$$
Consumption Smoothing
- So when $1+r = 1/\beta$, we get perfect consumption smoothing
- You can also show that when $1+r \ge 1/\beta$, you get $c < c^{\prime}$ and vice versa
- Makes sense: high interest rate $\rightarrow$ people save more
- Turns out this isn't too unreasonable, often $r$ is around $0.05$ and we usually use $\beta = 0.95$
$$(1+0.05) \times 0.95 \approx 1$$
A Specific Example
- Now let's specify a functional form for $u(\cdot)$ with
$$u(c) = \log(c)$$
- Thus our utility function, fully fledged, is given by
$$u(c,c^{\prime}) = \log(c) + \beta \log(c^{\prime})$$
- The Euler/MRS condition tells us the ratio of future to present consumption
$$1+g = \frac{c^{\prime}}{c} = \beta(1+r)$$
A Specific Example
- What about the exact levels of $c$ and $c^{\prime}$?
- We can get those from the budget constraint and the Euler equation combined
$$c = \left(\frac{1}{1+\beta}\right) we \qquad c^{\prime} = \left(\frac{\beta(1+r)}{1+\beta}\right) we$$
- Can also calculate savings $s = y - t - c$
$$s = \left(\frac{\beta}{1+\beta}\right) \left[y-t - \frac{y^{\prime}-t^{\prime}}{\beta(1+r)}\right]$$
Savings in the Data
Fairly large dispersion around 20% savings rate
Introducing a Government
- Let's think about the role of government now
- In US, federal government buys and sells bonds to affect interest rates
- Does so through the semi-independent Federal Reserve system
- Similar systems in place throughout most of the world
Historical Interest Rates
This shows the Federal Funds Rate since 1954
Government Budget
- Suppose we have a unitary government that
- Levies taxes $T$ and $T^{\prime}$
- Has spending levels $G$ and $G^{\prime}$
- Sells bonds $B$ to people at rate $r$
- This leads to present and future budget constraints
$$\begin{align*}
& G = T + B \\
& G^{\prime} + (1+r) B = T^{\prime}
\end{align*}$$
Government Present Value
- Now lets combine these two as we did with the consumers'
$$\begin{align*}
& G^{\prime} + (1+r) (G-T) = T^{\prime} \\
\Rightarrow\ & G + \frac{G^{\prime}}{1+r} = T + \frac{T^{\prime}}{1+r}
\end{align*}$$
- Just as before, the present value of government spending equals present value of government taxation
Connecting With Consumer
- When there $N$ consumers in the economy, the total tax amounts satisfy
$$T = t N$$
- Thus we can calculate the present value of each person's taxes
$$\begin{align*}
& T + \frac{T^{\prime}}{1+r} = G + \frac{G^{\prime}}{1+r} \\
\Rightarrow\ & t + \frac{t^{\prime}}{1+r} = \frac{1}{N}\left[G + \frac{G^{\prime}}{1+r}\right]
\end{align*}$$
Ricardian Equivalence
- In the consumer's budget equation we get
$$c + \frac{c^{\prime}}{1+r} = y + \frac{y^{\prime}}{1+r} - \frac{1}{N}\left[G + \frac{G^{\prime}}{1+r}\right]$$
- Thus the timing over government spending/taxes doesn't matter, only the present value does
- This notion is called Ricardian equivalence
- No change if the government reduced taxes today by $\$100$ and increased taxes tomorrow by $(1+r) \times \$100$ tomorrow (using $\$100$ increase in bonds $B$)
Consumer Response
Consumer will simply save extra after tax income: no change
Assumptions Invoked Here
- Tax changes are the same for all consumers in both present and future (no redistribution)
- Debt issued by the government is paid off during the lifetimes of the people alive when the debt was issued
- Taxes are "lump sum" rather than proportional (like income tax)
- Consumers and government face same interest rate and are free to borrow and lend
Real-world Example
- Does this apply to Bush tax cuts of 2001 (aka EGTRRA)?
- Reduced marginal income tax rates (graduated scheme)
- Credit constraints: went mostly to high earners, so not a big issue
- Taxes are proportional, not lump-sum, so they could be distortionary (reduce incentive to work)
- What will happen to future spending/taxation? People might expect lower spending in future
Government Debt Dynamics
- What happens when government runs consistent deficits?
$$\text{(Surplus)} \quad S = T - G$$
- Suppose that government runs a fixed surplus in each period
$$S_t = a Y_t = a (1+g)^t Y_0$$
- Surplus $a$ can be positive or negative (deficit), constant economic growth rate $g$
Debt Flows and Stocks
- Government debt is the accumulation of deficits over time
- Let the debt level be $D_t$ so that
$$D_t = (1+r)D_{t-1} - S_t = (1+r)D_{t-1} - a Y_t$$
- We want to think about the debt/GDP ratio $d_t = D_t/Y_t$
$$\begin{align*}
& \frac{D_t}{Y_t} = (1+r)\frac{D_{t-1}}{Y_t} - a = (1+r)\frac{D_{t-1}}{Y_{t-1}}\frac{Y_{t-1}}{Y_t} - a \\
\Rightarrow\ & d_t = \left(\frac{1+r}{1+g}\right) d_{t-1} - a
\end{align*}$$
Convergence of Debt/GDP
- Does this process converge? Use techniques we saw with capital growth ($k_t = k_{t-1} = k^{\ast}$)
- Suppose we always runs a deficit so that $a \lt 0$
- Then we need $r \lt g$ to converge!
$$\begin{align*}
& d_t = \left(\frac{1+r}{1+g}\right) d_{t-1} - a \\
\Rightarrow\ & d^{\ast} = \left(\frac{1+r}{1+g}\right) d^{\ast} - a = \frac{-a(1+g)}{g-r}
\end{align*}$$
Does It Converge?
- There are actually some reasons to think that $r \gt g$
- Right now $r \lt g$, but this has often not been the case
- From theory we saw earlier
$$1+g = \beta (1+r) \quad \Rightarrow \quad r \gt g$$
- In fact, the most concise three character summary of Piketty's recent Capital in the 21st Century is simply
$$"r \gt g"$$
Government Surplus Data
This is what it looks like for the US since 1950
Government Debt Data
This is what we see in the US since 1950
Aggregate Assumptions
- Suppose the primary deficit (the deficit minus interest payments on the government debt) is a constant fraction of GDP forever.
- Real GDP grows at its average rate, 3% per year, forever.
- The real interest rate is 2% per year, forever.
Steady State Calculations
- Primary deficit of 5% of GDP forever implies: Debt/GDP ratio of 515% in the long run, with 10.3% of GDP spent on interest payments on the government debt per year in the long run.
- Primary deficit of 2.5% of GDP forever implies: Debt/GDP ratio of 258% in the long run, with 5.2% of GDP spent on interest payments on the government debt.
Cross Country Data
Here we have central government debt for OECD countries